Skip to main content
Log in

A bankruptcy approach to solve the fixed cost allocation problem in transport systems

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
TOP Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we study the allocation of a fixed cost among different cities involved in a line-shape transport system like a tram line or a railway. The central characteristic of the problem is that the intended cost is not depending on the infrastructure length or the use intensity. Estañ et al. (Ann Oper Res 301(1):81–105, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-020-03645-1, 2021) originally introduced the problem and axiomatically studied it. Based on the well-known bankruptcy problem and game, we analyze it by applying two other approaches. First, adding a parameter, we take into account the municipalities revenues in the determination of cost shares. That enables one to transform a fixed cost allocation problem (FCAP) into a well-known bankruptcy one. We propose two bankruptcy problems for FCAP and use the proportional, adjusted proportional, constrained equal awards, constrained equal losses, and Talmud rules to solve it. Then, we define two bankruptcy games corresponding to FCAP and use the Shapley value for cost allocation. The characteristic functions have attractive interpretations; one considers the agents’ minimum desire to contribute to the cost, and the other does their minimum expectation from the overall profit. We investigate presented solutions if they meet some fairness and stability properties. Finally, we apply the suggested approaches to a practical problem.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aadland D, Kolpin V (1998) Shared irrigation costs: an empirical and axiomatic analysis. Math Soc Sci 35(2):203–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aumann RJ, Maschler M (1985) Game theoretic analysis of a bankruptcy problem from the Talmud. J Econ Theory 36(2):195–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergantiños G, Moreno-Ternero JD (2020) Sharing the revenues from broadcasting sport events. Manag Sci 66(6):2417–2431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cano-Berlanga S, Giménez-Gómez JM, Vilella C (2017) Enjoying cooperative games: the R package GameTheory. Appl Math Comput 305:381–393

    Google Scholar 

  • Casas-Méndez B, Fragnelli V, García-Jurado I (2011) Weighted bankruptcy rules and the museum pass problem. Eur J Oper Res 215(1):161–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chun Y (1988) The proportional solution for rights problems. Math Soc Sci 15(3):231–246

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curiel IJ, Maschler M, Tijs SH (1987) Bankruptcy games. Z Oper Res 31(5):A143–A159

    Google Scholar 

  • de Frutos MA (1999) Coalitional manipulations in a bankruptcy problem. Rev Econ Design 4(3):255–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dong B, Guo G, Wang Y (2012) Highway toll pricing. Eur J Oper Res 220(3):744–751

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutta B, Ray D (1989) A concept of egalitarianism under participation constraints. Econom J Econom Soc 57(3):615–635

    Google Scholar 

  • Estañ T, Llorca N, Martínez R, Sánchez-Soriano J (2020) Manipulability in the cost allocation of transport systems (No. 20/08) Department of Economic Theory and Economic History of the University of Granada

  • Estañ T, Llorca N, Martínez R, Sánchez-Soriano J (2021) On how to allocate the fixed cost of transport systems. Ann Oper Res 301(1):81–105. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-020-03645-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ginsburgh V, Moreno-Ternero JD (2018) Compensation schemes for learning a Lingua Franca in the European Union. World Econ 41(7):1775–1789

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ju B G, Miyagawa E (2002) Proportionality and non-manipulability in claims problems. Mimeo

  • Kuipers J, Mosquera MA, Zarzuelo JM (2013) Sharing costs in highways: a game theoretic approach. Eur J Oper Res 228(1):158–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Littlechild SC, Owen G (1973) A simple expression for the Shapley value in a special case. Manag Sci 20(3):370–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Littlechild SC, Owen G (1976) A further note on the nucleolus of the airport game. Int J Game Theory 5(2–3):91–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahini H (2021a) Bankruptcy Problem (https://www.mathworks.com/matlabcentral /fileexchange/69922-bankruptcy-problem), MATLAB Central File Exchange. Retrieved 1 Aug 2020

  • Mahini H (2021b) The Shapley value (https://www.mathworks.com/matlabcentral /fileexchange/69597-the-shapley-value), MATLAB Central File Exchange. Retrieved 1 Aug 2020

  • O’Neill B (1982) A problem of rights arbitration from the Talmud. Math Soc Sci 2(4):345–371

  • Schmeidler D (1969) The nucleolus of a characteristic function game. SIAM J Appl Math 17(6):1163–1170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapley LS (1953) A value for n-person games (II). In: Kuhn HW, Tucker AW (eds) Contributions to the theory of games (Annals of Mathematics Studies 28). Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 307–317

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomson W (2003) Axiomatic and game-theoretic analysis of bankruptcy and taxation problems: a survey. Math Soc Sci 45(3):249–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomson W (2007) Cost allocation and airport problems. Rochester Center for Economic Research, Working Paper (538)

  • Thomson W (2015) Axiomatic and game-theoretic analysis of bankruptcy and taxation problems: an update. Math Soc Sci 74:41–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tijs S (1981) Bounds for the core of a game and the t-value. In: Moeschlin O, Pallaschke D (eds) Game theory and mathematical economics. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 123–132

    Google Scholar 

  • Valencia-Toledo A, Vidal-Puga J (2018) Duality in land rental problems. Oper Res Lett 46(1):56–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors sincerely appreciate two anonymous reviewers for their useful comments and suggestions, which significantly improved quality of the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hamidreza Navidi.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Remark 1

Suppose x be a cost allocation prescribed by the AP, CEA, CEL, or TAL rules or the Shapley value of the bankruptcy game. In that case, it satisfies the null municipality, symmetry, and adjacent symmetry properties. In addition, it violates the additivity, weighted additivity, bilateral ratio consistency, trip decomposition, and no advantageous merging or splitting ones.

Proof

We present proof for the positive statements and counterexample for the negative ones.

  • Null municipality

    Consider the municipality i with \(\gamma _{gh} =\gamma _{hg} = 0\) for all \(s_g \in S_i\) and all \(s_h \in S\). Then, \(\Gamma _i=0\) and \(r_i=0\). The AP, CEA, CEL, and TAL rules satisfy claim boundedness, i.e., \(0\le x_i \le r_i\) (Thomson 2003). From the definition of the characteristic function of the bankruptcy game (3), the municipality i is a dummy player (\(v(D\cup \{i\})=v(D), \ \forall D\subset N\)). The Shapley value satisfies the dummy player property, i.e., \(\phi _i(v)=0\). Hence, if x is a cost allocation prescribed by the AP, CEA, CEL, and TAL rules or the Shapley value of the bankruptcy game, then \(x_i=0\).

  • Symmetry

    The AP, CEA, CEL, and TAL rules satisfy equal treatment of equals (Thomson 2003) that is equivalent to symmetry in the FCAP context. The characteristic function of the bankruptcy game preserves the municipalities symmetry, i.e., symmetric municipalities have the same marginal contributions to the coalitions. Shapley value also satisfies symmetry (Shapley 1953). Hence, the Shapley value of the bankruptcy game satisfies symmetry.

  • Adjacent symmetry

    Consider the \(fc=(M,S,F,C) \in {{\mathbb {F}}}{{\mathbb {C}}}\). Suppose that there exist \(\{i,j\}\subset M\) such that \(\gamma _{gh}+\gamma _{hg}=\Gamma (F)\), \(|g-h|=1\), \(g \in S_i\), and \(h \in S_j\). Therefore (a)\(\gamma _{lp}=0\) for all \(l, p \in S\setminus \{g,h\}\) and (b)\(\Gamma _i(F)=\Gamma _j(F)\). (a) shows that each \(k \in M\setminus \{i,j\}\), is a null municipality. (b) implies that municipalities i and j are symmetric. Hence, \(x_i=x_j=\frac{C}{2}\).

  • Additivity and weighted additivity

    Consider \(fc = (M, S, F, C)\) with \(M = \{ 1, 2, 3 \}\), \(S = \{ S_1 = \{s_1\}, S_2 = \{s_2\}, S_3 = \{s_3\} \}\), and the following flow matrix and cost:

    $$\begin{aligned} F=\begin{pmatrix}0 &{}\quad 1&{}\quad 1 \\ 1 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 1 \\ 1 &{}\quad 1 &{}\quad 0 \end{pmatrix},\ C=6. \end{aligned}$$

    Then, consider \(fc'=(M,S,F',C')\) and \(fc''=(M,S,F'',C'')\) with

    $$\begin{aligned} F'=\begin{pmatrix}0 &{}\quad 0&{}\quad 0 \\ 0 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 1 \\ 0 &{}\quad 1 &{}\quad 0 \end{pmatrix},\ C'=2,\quad F''=\begin{pmatrix}0 &{}\quad 1&{}\quad 1 \\ 1 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0 \\ 1 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0 \end{pmatrix},\ C''=4. \end{aligned}$$

    Table 10 demonstrates the results for \(B=1.5\) showing the violation of the additivity property by the AP, CEA, TAL, and Shapley value. Here and in the following tables in this section, BP stands for bankruptcy problem. Doing some calculation, one can observe that the example also shows that weighted additivity is not met.

  • Bilateral ratio consistency

    Consider the \(fc = (M,S,F,C)\) where

    $$\begin{aligned} M&=\{1,2,3\}, \\ S&=\{S_1=\{s_1\},S_2=\{s_2, s_3\},S_3=\{s_4\}\},\\ F&=\begin{pmatrix} 0 &{}\quad 2 &{}\quad 3 &{}\quad 1\\ 2 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 4 &{}\quad 0 \\ 0 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 2\\ 0 &{}\quad 2 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0 \end{pmatrix},\\ C&=11. \end{aligned}$$

    Now, consider the problem \(fc' = (M', S', F',C)\) where \(M'=\{1,2\}\),\(S'=S_1\cup S_2\), \(F' = F_{\{1,2\}}\). Table 11 demonstrates the results for \(B=0.5\) showing that the requirement of bilateral ratio consistency is not met.

  • Trip decomposition

    Let fc be the FCAP of Example 1. Now consider \(fc'=(M, S, F', C)\) with \(F'\) as the following flow matrix resulted by the decomposition of the two trips from station \(s_1\) to \(s_3\) to the trips from \(s_1\) to \(s_2\) and from \(s_2\) to \(s_3\):

    $$\begin{aligned} F'=\begin{pmatrix} 0 &{}\quad 5 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0 \\ 1 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 2 &{}\quad 0 \\ 5 &{}\quad 2 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0\\ 0 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0 \end{pmatrix}. \end{aligned}$$

    Table 12 shows the result for fc and \(fc'\) for \(B=0.5\) which demonstrate that the Shapley value, AP, CEA, CEL, and TAL do not meet the requirement of trip decomposition.

  • No advantageous merging or splitting

    Again let fc be the FCAP of Example 1. Now consider \(fc' = (M',S',F,C)\) that differs from fc in the splitting of municipality 2 with two stations into two municipalities with one station; i.e., \(M'=\{1,2,3,4\}\) and

    $$\begin{aligned} S'=\{S'_1=\{s_1\},S'_2=\{s_2\},S'_3=\{s_3\},S'_4=\{s_4\}\}. \end{aligned}$$

    Table 13 shows the results for both problems for \(B=1\). One can observe that for the AP, CEA, TAL, and the Shapley value, merging is advantageous, and for the CEL, splitting is advantageous.

\(\square \)

Table 10 Examples for violation of the additivity property by the Shapley value, AP, CEA, CEL, and TAL
Table 11 Examples for violation of the bilateral ratio consistency property by the Shapley value, AP, CEA, CEL, and TAL
Table 12 Examples for violation of the trip decomposition property by the Shapley value, AP, CEA, CEL, and TAL
Table 13 Examples for violation of the no advantageous merging or splitting property by the Shapley value, AP, CEA, CEL, and TAL

Remark 2

If x be a cost allocation prescribed by the PROP rule, it satisfies the null municipality, symmetry, adjacent symmetry, weighted additivity, and no advantageous merging or splitting properties. In addition, it violates the additivity, bilateral ratio consistency, and trip decomposition ones.

Proof

According to the Theorem 1, the proportional rule satisfies null municipality, symmetry, and weighted additivity. We prove that it meets the requirements of no advantageous merging or splitting and adjacent symmetry and give counterexamples for the remaining ones.

  • No advantageous merging or splitting

    Consider two FCAPs, \(fc=(M, S, F, C)\) and \({fc}'=(M', S', F, C)\) such that \(M'\subset M\). Suppose that there is \(i \in M'\) such that \(S'_i=S_i\cup (\cup _{j \in M\setminus M'}S_j)\), and for each \(j\in M'\setminus \{i\}, S'_j=S_j\). It implies that \(\Gamma '_i=\Gamma _i + \sum _{j\in M\setminus M'}\Gamma _j\) and \(\sum _{j\in M'}\Gamma '_j=\sum _{j\in M}\Gamma _j\). Therefore, we have

    $$\begin{aligned} {\text {PROP}}_i(M', S', F, C)&= \frac{\Gamma '_i}{\sum _{j\in M'}\Gamma '_j}\times C,\\ {}&=\frac{(\Gamma _i + \sum _{j\in M\setminus M'}\Gamma _j)}{\sum _{j\in M}\Gamma _j}\times C,\\ {}&={\text {PROP}}_i(M, S, F, C)+\sum _{j \in M\setminus M'}{\text {PROP}}_j(M, S, F, C). \end{aligned}$$
  • Adjacent symmetry

    Consider the \(fc=(M,S,F,C) \in {{\mathbb {F}}}{{\mathbb {C}}}\). Suppose that there exist \(\{i,j\}\subset M\) such that \(\gamma _{gh}+\gamma _{hg}=\Gamma (F)\), \(|g-h|=1\), \(g \in S_i\), and \(h \in S_j\). Therefore (a)\(\gamma _{lp}=0\) for all \(l, p \in S\setminus \{g,h\}\) and (b)\(\Gamma _i(F)=\Gamma _j(F)\). (a) shows that each \(k \in M\setminus \{i,j\}\), is a null municipality. (b) implies that municipalities i and j are symmetric. Since the proportional rule satisfies null municipality and symmetry and x is efficient, \(x_i=x_j=\frac{C}{2}\).

  • Additivity

    Let (MSFC) be the FCAP of Example 1 and consider \((M,S,F',C')\) and \((M,S,F'',C'')\) with

    $$\begin{aligned} F'=\begin{pmatrix}0 &{}\quad 3&{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0\\ 1 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0 \\ 1 &{}\quad 2 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0\\ 0&{}\quad 0&{}\quad 0&{}\quad 0\end{pmatrix}, C'=7,\quad F''=\begin{pmatrix}0 &{}\quad 1&{}\quad 2 &{}\quad 0\\ 0 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 1 &{}\quad 0 \\ 4 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 0\\ 0&{}\quad 0&{}\quad 0&{}\quad 0\end{pmatrix}, C''=5. \end{aligned}$$

    Then, we have

    $$\begin{aligned}&{\text {PROP}}(M,S,F,C) = (4.8, 7.2, 0),\\&{\text {PROP}}(M,S,F',C') = (2.5, 4.5, 0),\\&{\text {PROP}}(M,S,F'',C'')= (2.1875, 2.8125, 0). \end{aligned}$$

    One can observe that while \(F=F'+F''\) and \(C=C'+C''\),

    $$\begin{aligned} {\text {PROP}}(M,S,F,C)\ne {\text {PROP}}(M,S,F',C')+{\text {PROP}}(M,S,F'',C''). \end{aligned}$$

    Note that the prescription of the proportional rule is independent of the value of the parameter B.

  • Bilateral ratio consistency

    Consider the \(fc=(M,S,F,C)\) where

    $$\begin{aligned} M&=\{1,2,3\}, \\ S&=\{S_1=\{s_1\},S_2=\{s_2\},S_3=\{s_3\}\},\\ F&=\begin{pmatrix} 0 &{}\quad 2 &{}\quad 3 \\ 1 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad 1 \\ 0 &{}\quad 4 &{}\quad 0 \end{pmatrix},\\ C&=5. \end{aligned}$$

    Then, we have \({\text {PROP}}(fc)=(1.3636, 1.8182, 1.8182)\). Now consider the problem \((\{1,2\},S_1\cup S_2,F_{\{1,2\}}, 5)\). Here, the proportional rule prescribes (2.5, 2.5) for municipalities 1 and 2. Thus, the requirement of bilateral ratio consistency is not met.

  • Trip decomposition

    Consider the problems fc and \(fc'\) presented in Remark 1 for the trip decomposition item. Then, \({\text {PROP}}(fc) = (4.8, 7.2, 0)\), and \({\text {PROP}}(fc') = (4.4, 7.6, 0)\). One can observe that \({\text {PROP}}(fc)\ne {\text {PROP}}(fc')\) and the trip decomposition is not satisfied.

\(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Babaei, F., Navidi, H. & Moretti, S. A bankruptcy approach to solve the fixed cost allocation problem in transport systems. TOP 30, 332–358 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11750-021-00618-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11750-021-00618-w

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification

Navigation